This package implements the schumaker spline for one dimensional interpolation. This is the first publicly available R package to give a shape-constrained spline without any optimisation being necessary. It also has significant speed advantages compared to the other shape constrained splines. It is intended for use in dynamic programming problems and in other cases where a simple shape constrained spline is useful.
This vignette first illustrates that the base splines can deliver nonconcave splines from concave data. It follows by describing the options that the schumaker spline provides. It then describes a consumption smoothing problem before illustrating why the schumaker spline performs significantly better than existing splines in these applications.
Finally the speed of this spline in comparison with other splines is described.
We can show that base splines are not shape preserving. Now we can plot the monotonic spline (you can experiment with the other ones for a similar result):
x = seq(1,10)
y = log(x)
xarray = seq(1,10,0.01)
BaseSpline = splinefun(x,y, method = "monoH.FC")
Base0 = BaseSpline(xarray)
DerivBaseSpline = splinefun(xarray, numDeriv::grad(BaseSpline, xarray))
Base1 = DerivBaseSpline(xarray)
Deriv2BaseSpline = splinefun(xarray, numDeriv::grad(DerivBaseSpline, xarray))
Base2 = Deriv2BaseSpline(xarray)
plot(xarray, Base0, type = "l", col = 4, ylim = c(-1,3), main = "Base Spline and first two derivatives",
ylab = "Spline and derivatives", xlab = "x")
lines(xarray, Base1, col = 2)
lines(xarray, Base2, col = 3)
abline(h = 0, col = 1)
text(x=rep(8,8,8), y=c(2, 0.5,-0.2), pos=4, labels=c('Spline', 'First Derivative', 'Second Derivative'))
Here you can see that the first derivative is always positive - the spline is monotonic. However the second derivative moves above and below 0. The spline is not globally concave.
Now we can show the schumaker spline:
library(schumaker)
SchumSpline = schumaker::Schumaker(x,y)
Schum0 = SchumSpline$Spline(xarray)
Schum1 = SchumSpline$DerivativeSpline(xarray)
Schum2 = SchumSpline$SecondDerivativeSpline(xarray)
plot(xarray, Schum0, type = "l", col = 4, ylim = c(-1,3), main = "Schumaker Spline and first two derivatives",
ylab = "Spline and derivatives", xlab = "x")
lines(xarray, Schum1, col = 2)
lines(xarray, Schum2, col = 3)
abline(h = 0, col = 1)
text(x=rep(8,8,8), y=c(2, 0.5,-0.2), pos=4, labels=c('Spline', 'First Derivative', 'Second Derivative'))
Here the second derivative is always negative - the spline is globally concave as well as monotonic.
There are three optional setting in creating a spline. Firstly the gradients at each of the (x,y) points can be input to give more accuracy. If not supplied these are estimated from the points.
Secondly if Vectorised = TRUE arrays can be input to the spline. If arrays will never be input to the spline then you can set Vectorised = FALSE for a small speed improvement (about 30%).
Finally there are three options for out of sample prediction.
Curve - This is where the quadratic curve that is present in the first and last interval are used to predict points before the first interval and after the last interval respectively.
Linear - This is where a line is extended out before the first interval and after the last interval. The slope of the line is given by the derivative at the start of the first interval and end of the last interval.
Constant - This is where the first and last y values are used for prediction before the first point of the interval and after the last part of the interval respectively.
The three out of sample options are shown below. Here you can see in black the curve is extended out. In green the ends are extrapolated linearly whilst red has constant extrapolation. Note that there is no difference between the 3 within sample.
x = seq(1,10)
y = log(x)
xarray = seq(-5,15,0.01)
SchumSplineCurve = Schumaker(x,y, Extrapolation = "Curve" )$Spline
SchumSplineConstant = Schumaker(x,y, Extrapolation = "Constant")$Spline
SchumSplineLinear = Schumaker(x,y, Extrapolation = "Linear" )$Spline
SchumSplineCurveVals = SchumSplineCurve(xarray)
SchumSplineConstantVals = SchumSplineConstant(xarray)
SchumSplineLinearVals = SchumSplineLinear(xarray)
plot(xarray, SchumSplineCurveVals, type = "l", col = 1, ylim = c(-5,5),
main = "Ways of predicting outside of sample", ylab = "Spline value", xlab = "x")
lines(xarray, SchumSplineConstantVals, col = 2)
lines(xarray, SchumSplineLinearVals, col = 3)
Consider a consumer that has a budget of \(B_t\) at time \(t\) and a periodic income of \(1\). They have a periodic utility function given by:
\(u_t = \epsilon_t x_t^{0.2}\)
where \(x_t\) is spending in period \(t\) and \(\epsilon_t\) is the shock in period \(t\) drawn from some stationary nonnegative shock process with pdf \(f(\epsilon)\).
The problem for the consumer in period \(t\) is:
\(V(B_t | \epsilon_{t}) = \max_{0 < x_t < B} \hspace{0.5cm} \epsilon_t x_t^{0.2} + \beta E_t[ V(B_{t+1})]\)
Where \(\beta\) is a discounting factor and \(B_{t+1} = 1 + B_t - x_t\).
We can first note that due to the shock process it is not possible to get analytical equations to describe the paths of spending and the budget over the long term. We can get a numerical solution however. The key step is to find expressions for the expected value function as a function of \(B_{t+1}\). With this we can run simulations with random shocks to see the long term distributions of \(x_t\) and \(B_t\). The algorithm we will use is:
This strategy relies on the consumption problem being a contraction mapping. This means that if we use this algorithm we will converge to a fixed point function. The turboem package (squareem method) can be useful here in accelerating the convergence.
There are a few reasons we need the spline to be shape preserving and without optimization to make this work:
Shape preservation is necessary so the spline is globally concave (the \(V(B_t | \epsilon_t )\) values will always be concave as the periodic utility function is always concave). This is necessary for the one dimensional optimisation step. The periodic utility function is concave and the future value function needs to be concave (in \(B_{t+1}\)) to guarantee a unique local optima. Other splines can incorporate convexities in the intervals between interpolation points which can lead to multiple local optima.
There do exist shape preserving splines that incorporate an optimization step (ie scam, cobs). These are not effective for this kind of problem because it is not possible to converge to a fixed point. In each iteration the optimization settles on a slightly different parameter set which means the future value function can “jump around”. In addition the optimization step can take a significant amount of time because evaluations of the future value function spline take longer.
These microbenchmarks are available below:
library(microbenchmark)
library(cobs)
library(scam)
## Loading required package: mgcv
## Loading required package: nlme
## This is mgcv 1.8-7. For overview type 'help("mgcv-package")'.
## This is scam 1.1-9.
x = seq(1,10)
y = log(x)
dat = data.frame(x = x, y = y)
xarray = seq(0,15,0.01)
microbenchmark(
Schumaker(x,y),
splinefun(x,y,"monoH.FC"),
scam(y~s(x,k=4,bs="mdcx",m=1),data=dat),
cobs(x , y, constraint = c("decrease", "convex"), print.mesg = FALSE),
unit = "relative"
)
## Unit: relative
## expr
## Schumaker(x, y)
## splinefun(x, y, "monoH.FC")
## scam(y ~ s(x, k = 4, bs = "mdcx", m = 1), data = dat)
## cobs(x, y, constraint = c("decrease", "convex"), print.mesg = FALSE)
## min lq mean median uq max neval
## 290.8048 182.0341 171.7828 160.6800 159.4023 149.0093 100
## 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 100
## 459.5418 284.5107 267.4622 249.5471 241.5509 413.1629 100
## 778.9557 477.5648 446.6378 423.6692 400.2666 499.0156 100
BaseSp = splinefun(x,y,"monoH.FC")
SchuSp = Schumaker(x,y)$Spline
ScamSp = scam(y~s(x,k=4,bs="mdcx",m=1),data=dat)
CobsSp = cobs(x , y, constraint = c("decrease", "convex"), print.mesg = FALSE)
ScamPr = function(x){ predict.scam(ScamSp,data.frame(x = x))}
CobsPr = function(x){ predict(CobsSp, x)[,2] }
microbenchmark(
SchuSp(xarray),
BaseSp(xarray),
ScamPr(xarray),
CobsPr(xarray),
unit = "relative"
)
## Unit: relative
## expr min lq mean median uq
## SchuSp(xarray) 1.000000 1.000000 1.0000000 1.000000 1.000000
## BaseSp(xarray) 1.562945 1.545315 0.2244708 1.608311 1.704043
## ScamPr(xarray) 39.720369 41.896859 4.8171019 43.053354 41.439299
## CobsPr(xarray) 1.157347 1.203131 0.1667256 1.330860 1.494132
## max neval
## 1.000000000 100
## 0.020448538 100
## 0.085249099 100
## 0.005399734 100
SchuSp = Schumaker(x,y, Vectorise = FALSE)$Spline
microbenchmark(
SchuSp(runif(1)),
BaseSp(runif(1)),
ScamPr(runif(1)),
CobsPr(runif(1)),
unit = "relative"
)
## Unit: relative
## expr min lq mean median uq
## SchuSp(runif(1)) 1.00000 1.00000 1.000000 1.000000 1.000000
## BaseSp(runif(1)) 6.00000 5.17110 3.906418 4.389837 3.941156
## ScamPr(runif(1)) 337.83831 272.69457 135.619490 186.661888 144.999025
## CobsPr(runif(1)) 12.25025 10.48503 7.292844 8.644082 8.152931
## max neval
## 1.000000 100
## 1.648775 100
## 19.447854 100
## 2.072086 100
The key reference for the schumaker spline is Judd’s Numerical Methods in Economics (1998). This presents precisely how to create the spline and it is simple to reconcile the code with the equations from this book. This book also gives more detail on solving dynamic control problems. A further reference which advocates the use of the schumaker spline is Ljungqvist and Sargent’s Recursive Economic Theory.